According to the story in the L.A. Times:
http://www.latimes.com/business/la-fi-ucla-doctor-conflicts-20140423,0,3924175.story#axzz2zwLITYhU
--there are two versions of what happened; so to be as fair as possible I'll first give UCLA's version.
Dr. Robert Pedowitz became chair of the orthopedic surgery department at the medical school in 2009. After voicing his concerns to higher officials about how many of his colleagues were taking industry money, in a manner he described as negatively affecting patient care, he stepped down in 2010. In 2012 he sued UCLA and some of his colleagues, charging retaliation for his speaking out, in the form of interfering with his getting research grants and patient referrals.
UCLA investigated the charges Dr. Pedowitz had brought and found a few irregularities, but mostly that no laws or university rules had been violated, and patients had not been compromised. Despite this clean bill of health, the UC regents have now decided to settle with the doctor to the tune of $10M, not because they're admitting any wrongdoing, but to "avoid the 'substantial expense and inconvenience' of further litigation."
Now for the other side of the story. Dr. Pedowitz (noting that the problems he faced are rife among academic medical cents and hardly are unique to UCLA) found when he came on board that one surgeon in his department was being paid $250,000 by the device maker Medtronic for consulting work. That same physician was trying to enroll patients in a research project involving Medtronic products. Sen. Charles Grassley (R-IA) had previously spotlighted a UCLA spine surgeon who had accepted $460,000 from Medtronic and other companies but had somehow failed to disclose these payments. UCLA, Pedowitz and his attorney charge, was too interested in the money to be made by these surgeons and by their potential commercial discoveries to rein in these practices.
I won't say who's right in this dispute, except to note that last time I checked, you could buy an awful lot of legal expense and inconvenience for $10M; so you can draw your own conclusions of which side the UC regents thought was going to win had the case gone all the way through the court.
Friday, April 25, 2014
Friday, April 18, 2014
“Breakthrough Cures”? Reasons for Skepticism
Earlier this week I posted about the current issue of the New England Journal, and mentioned in
passing the appearance of antiviral drugs for hepatitis C that are being touted
as new miracle cures. My focus in that post—
http://brodyhooked.blogspot.com/2014/04/summarizing-market-failure-special.html
--was how our so-called free market fails to protect the public interest, so I looked only at the outrageous cost of the hepatitis C drugs and gave a free pass, more or less, to the “cure” claims.
http://hcrenewal.blogspot.com/2014/03/too-good-to-be-true-sovaldi-kerfuffle.html
--about how it’s a mathematical near-certainty that the first reports about any new drug will give an unduly rosy picture of its effectiveness.)
http://brodyhooked.blogspot.com/2014/04/summarizing-market-failure-special.html
--was how our so-called free market fails to protect the public interest, so I looked only at the outrageous cost of the hepatitis C drugs and gave a free pass, more or less, to the “cure” claims.
In doing so I overlooked an older and a more recent blog
post by our good pal Dr. Roy Poses at Health Care Renewal:
http://hcrenewal.blogspot.com/2014/04/knee-deep-in-hoopla-triumph-of-medical.htmlhttp://hcrenewal.blogspot.com/2014/03/too-good-to-be-true-sovaldi-kerfuffle.html
Dr. Poses takes care to show the extraordinarily flimsy
evidence on which these new drugs are being ballyhooed. He says a number of
things about study design and so on, all of which seem pertinent. But if we try
to get a sense of the big picture, all I think we need to know is the natural
history of hepatitis C. As Dr. Poses reviews for us, hepatitis C can be a very
bad disease leading to liver failure and death. But the total number of folks
with the virus who end up with this extreme version of the disease is not that
large. A goodly number of people who carry the hepatitis C virus never develop
any obvious disease at all. Another good chuck of them develop some liver
inflammation, but it never develops into the extreme life-threatening forms.
So before one can get all that excited about a new treatment
for hepatitis C, insofar as actual patient-centered outcomes are concerned,
we’d need a large-scale follow-up study that showed that people getting the new
drugs actually had improved health over the long haul. That would in turn
depend on showing that the apparently decent (but hardly perfect) side effect
profile of the new drugs is maintained long-term, else the chance of having a
bad side effect might be as great as the chance one would have had the bad kind
of rapidly-advancing hepatitis C infection with liver damage.
According to Dr. Poses who’s checked out the literature much
more carefully than I have, what we know so far is that the new drugs do a
pretty good job of clearing the hepatitis C virus from the bloodstreams of
patients when followed for a period of up to 24 weeks.
It may well be that a drug that does this good a job of
clearing the virus in the short term does an equally good job of saving the
patient from long-term, serious consequences of having the virus. Or that may
not be the case—we’ve seen many, many instances of initially promising
treatments that ultimately fail to pass that test. (This may also be a good
time here to remind ourselves of Dr. John Ioannidis’s warning:
http://brodyhooked.blogspot.com/2011/03/how-honest-reports-of-research-can.html--about how it’s a mathematical near-certainty that the first reports about any new drug will give an unduly rosy picture of its effectiveness.)
Now, let’s be fair to the advocates for the new drug. It
will take years, to say nothing of tons of money, to do the studies needed to
show the real effectiveness of these new hepatitis C drugs. So in the meantime,
the data we have so far is probably what’s to be expected at this stage. And so
far, the drug is performing more or less as one would expect if indeed it is
going to turn out to be a breakthrough drug.
OK, I’ll buy all that. So how about some recognition of the
actual limitations of what we know, when this drug is being talked about? Why
should supposedly scientifically-aware advocates for the drug feel a need to talk
like used car salesmen? (Unless, in fact, their ultimate goal is to sell us a
clunker?)
So mea culpa for
my earlier post, if I inadvertently added to the hype around these new drugs,
instead of joining Dr. Poses in raising the appropriate skeptical concerns. One
can hope that the drugs turn out to be what they are hoped to be; and one can
also hope that somehow, if that’s the case, people who need them will be able
to afford them.
The History of US Drug Policy Since the Cold War
One theme in HOOKED is the need to see today’s relationship
between the medical profession and the pharmaceutical industry in proper
historical context. When HOOKED was written, I had to struggle, as a non-historian,
to try to put together an adequate historical background picture. Since then,
useful books have appeared that make that task easier.
--is the impact of the ideology that I prefer to call economism and others call neoliberalism on today’s Pharma policy. Prof. Tobbell was kind enough to respond to an e-mail query, since I noted that the word “neoliberalism” is virtually absent from her volume. Consistent with her thesis, she states that the anti-government-regulation, pro-free-market stance that the drug industry has adopted was present all through the 1950s and 1960s. When neoliberalism/economism entered the US political discourse in a big way in the middle to late 1970s, Pharma was happy to hitch its wagon to that rising star, just as it was happy to jump on the anticommunist bandwagon in earlier decades; but one cannot say that neoliberalism played a major formative role in Pharma’s policy or strategic thinking.
Prof. Dominique Tobbell of the University of Minnesota has
contributed Pills, Power, and Policy: The
Struggle for Drug Reform in Cold War America and Its Consequences. She
makes two basic points about our struggle today to reform drug policy, in a
direction that brings pharmaceutical manufacture, research, and marketing
better into line with public health and public interest. The first point is
that this struggle is not new; basically the same issues have recurred ever
since the end of World War II. The second point is that the pharmaceutical
industry has never waged this battle against what it considers burdensome government
regulation on its own; it has always had allies among medical organizations and
academic physicians who had a strong interest in defending the status quo.
Prof. Tobbell points out that by the mid-1960s, the drug
industry had achieved an impressive enough record in fighting off government
regulation that the tobacco industry turned to Pharma for advice and help.
During all those years, medical practitioners were primed by the AMA to fear
the bogeyman of socialized medicine, and academic physicians worried about
excessive federal influence over research policies. It was easy to get these
fellow travelers on board when Pharma wrapped itself in the mantle of “free
enterprise” and presented a less-regulated industry to Congress and to the
American public as a bulwark against communism.
In the heady postwar days, when everyone was thrilled with
the tremendous advances in antibiotic, hormonal, and psychiatric therapy, the
climate of ethical thought was quite different from what reigns today. For
example, Prof. Tobbell describes the efforts at the University of Pennsylvania
to create a training program in clinical pharmacology in 1955: “Norman
Topping, the university’s vice-president in charge of medical affairs, sought
to create an institutional structure that would ensure the program could be
responsive to the industry’s needs. Indeed, Topping believed the new program
should function, essentially, as a service unit for the drug industry.”While
today such a stance would at least raise some eyebrows, apparently no one gave
it a second glance in the 1950s.
Similarly, when the National Academy of Sciences formed the
Drug Research Board in 1963, to help conduct the massive amount of research
required to implement the new FDA amendments Congress had just passed to
require that drugs be shown to be effective as well as safe, some in Congress
looked askance at the inclusion of scientists with strong industry ties. The
Board basically pooh-poohed any such concerns, insisting that it was a great
advantage to have these scientists as part of the effort because of their
inside knowledge and policy smarts. Conflict of interest—who, us?
One theme that I have addressed at some length in earlier
posts—most recently:
http://brodyhooked.blogspot.com/2014/03/a-bit-of-history-louis-lasagna-and.html--is the impact of the ideology that I prefer to call economism and others call neoliberalism on today’s Pharma policy. Prof. Tobbell was kind enough to respond to an e-mail query, since I noted that the word “neoliberalism” is virtually absent from her volume. Consistent with her thesis, she states that the anti-government-regulation, pro-free-market stance that the drug industry has adopted was present all through the 1950s and 1960s. When neoliberalism/economism entered the US political discourse in a big way in the middle to late 1970s, Pharma was happy to hitch its wagon to that rising star, just as it was happy to jump on the anticommunist bandwagon in earlier decades; but one cannot say that neoliberalism played a major formative role in Pharma’s policy or strategic thinking.
Dominique A. Tobbell, Pills,
Power, and Policy: The Struggle for Drug Reform in Cold War America and Its Consequences.
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press/Milbank Books on Health and the
Public, 2012.
Thursday, April 17, 2014
Yet More on Statins and the Recent Guidelines
Not to make this blog the “Statins Blog” or anything, but
since I have been on a tear regarding the unfortunate ACC/AHA guidelines on
cholesterol:
http://brodyhooked.blogspot.com/2013/12/more-on-cholesterol-guidelines-cochrane.html
--and since my pals at Primary Care Medical Abstracts keep feeding me more ammunition, I wanted briefly to mention two more commentaries that take aim at the guidelines (subscriptions probably required to access).
http://brodyhooked.blogspot.com/2013/12/more-on-cholesterol-guidelines-cochrane.html
--and since my pals at Primary Care Medical Abstracts keep feeding me more ammunition, I wanted briefly to mention two more commentaries that take aim at the guidelines (subscriptions probably required to access).
First, John Abramson, who’s been mentioned here numerous
times, and his colleagues wrote in BMJ
about the CTT meta-analysis, on which the new guidelines heavily relied. They
challenged the rosy picture painted by the CTT by drilling down and recalculating
the CTT’s own numbers. The CTT, recall, claimed that if one carefully summed
the data from numerous previous clinical trials (none of which showed any
reduction in all-cause mortality from taking statins for primary prevention),
you could see that statins in low-risk patients save lives and prevent strokes
and heart attacks.
So when Abramson’s team went back and crunched the numbers
themselves they found, for the populations included in these studies:
- No significant difference in all-cause mortality
- You’d have to treat 140 low risk patients for 5 years to prevent one heart attack or stroke
- The studies overall either fail to report any adverse reactions to statins, or else report adverse reactions at a much lower rate than has been shown in independent (non-manufacturer-sponsored) studies. If the rates of adverse reactions in the independent studies are valid, it is very likely that the chance of suffering an adverse reaction from a statin is notably greater than the chance of preventing a bad outcome.
Ioannidis takes a step back then and asks the question—we’ve
been in the business of trying to calculate risk of coronary artery disease for
more than 30 years; so how come we still can’t get it right? He also notes that
the decision on the part of the guideline writers that a 10 year risk of
developing cardiovascular disease of 7.5% ought to be the cutoff for
recommending statins is a completely arbitrary number, unsupported by any
empirical evidence—the “right” number could be 2% or 20% for all we know.
What these commentaries have in common is that both point
out how messed up the basic data are due to all the major studies being
supported by the drug industry, and how serious conflicts of interest
contaminate this entire enterprise.
Abramson JD, Rosenberg HG, Jewell N, Wright JM. “Should
People at Low Risk for Cardiovascular Disease Take a Statin?” BMJ 347:f6123, 2013.
Ioannidis JPA. “More Than a Billion People Taking Statins?
Potential Implications of the New Cardiovascular Guidelines.” JAMA 311:463-464, Feb. 5, 2014.
Summarizing the “Market Failure” Special Issue of the New England Journal
Three articles in this week’s New England Journal of Medicine all combine to illustrate “market
failure” in the pharmaceutical industry. As you can guess, the editors of NEJM
didn’t adopt my suggested title for their issue. (See the end if you want more
explanation as to why I’m calling it that.)
--that talks about what would ordinarily be considered unalloyed good news elsewhere in the issue. Hepatitis C, which up till now has been quite resistant to treatment, appears to be well controlled by a new family of antiviral medications, with a minimum of side effects. This indeed appears to be one of those all-too-rare-today “breakthroughs” in drug treatment.
OK, so we have three articles in the same issue of NEJM, all of which have the same basic theme—in the name of profits, the drug industry is working contrary to the public health and the advancement of science. This is what old-time economist Kenneth Arrow famously called the market failure of health care—it simply does not follow the laws of supply and demand. Those who continue to extol the supposedly “free” market as the right way to manage all of our affairs, pharmaceuticals and health included, have to stick their heads in the sand and pretend that market failure never happens. As this blog has shown extensively, it happens all the time.
First is the editorial by Drs. Hoofnagle and Sherker—
http://www.nejm.org/doi/full/10.1056/NEJMe1401508----that talks about what would ordinarily be considered unalloyed good news elsewhere in the issue. Hepatitis C, which up till now has been quite resistant to treatment, appears to be well controlled by a new family of antiviral medications, with a minimum of side effects. This indeed appears to be one of those all-too-rare-today “breakthroughs” in drug treatment.
So what’s not to like? As the editorialists explain, the
price tag. A complete course of one of the drugs comes in at $84,000, which
works out to $1000 per tablet. The authors note a collision course between
newly expanded public health efforts to do a better job of detecting the
additional 1.6 million Americans who have Hep C and don’t know it, so that they
can get this wonderful new treatment, which then many of them will not be able
to afford—or if we could provide it for them, would break the bank of what the
authors delicately call an “already overburdened medical care system.”
The authors work for the NIH and as dutiful government employees are apparently
discouraged from saying anything bad about the pharmaceutical industry, so they
offer no ideas on what might be done about this problem.
Now jump to two “Perspectives” pieces in the same issue. One
is from our good friends at the Harvard-Brigham and Women’s program in
Pharmacoepidemiology and Pharmacoeconomics, including Dr. Jerry Avorn:
http://www.nejm.org/doi/full/10.1056/NEJMp1400488
The P&P gang describes what has happened under a program
begun by the FDA in 2007, the Risk Evaluation and Mitigation Strategy. The idea
when this passed Congress was to speed the entry onto the market of useful new
medications that also posed safety issues. If the company could come up with a
special plan to limit the use of the drug in such a way as to lower the risk of
adverse reactions, then the drug could go on the market. But the proviso added
on was that this plan ought not be used as a way to stop generic products from
entering the market later.
Unfortunately the amendments that passed Congress also
included a monkey wrench that was virtually guaranteed to undermine this intent
(assuming that Congress intended what they said, and that Pharma lobbyists did
not rewrite the law in the back room). The company that developed this special
safety plan for the new drug could also patent the plan.
So Dr. Avorn and colleagues list several cases where the
drug company has sued generic competitors claiming patent infringement if the
generic guys use the same safety plan, and also filing suit to stop any generic
that uses a different safety plan as raising the risk level for the public
unacceptably. The only sensible way to fix this problem, say the Harvard guys,
is to use the same safety plan for all versions of the drug regardless of
manufacturer, but to make this happen Congress would probably have to amend the
2007 act. Bottom line—a policy that was intended to allow patients access to
drugs while assuring safety, that was not supposed to interfere with generics
entering the market, is being used by Pharma precisely as an “evergreening”
tool to prevent generic competition.
Now we come to another Perspectives article authored by Drs.
Sham Mailankody and Vinay Prasad:
http://www.nejm.org/doi/full/10.1056/NEJMp1400104
They also address the cost of new drugs, in this instance
for cancer. Their basic point is—there are newly developed drugs for cancer treatment
that provide small but apparently real benefits, such as an average extension
of life by a few months. These drugs work by mechanisms very similar to old,
generic drugs. (They give the example of the new drug abiraterone, which works
in much the same way as an old anti-fungal antibiotic, ketoconazole.) So the
ideal scientific question now to be asked is how well these same cancer
patients would do if instead of getting the very expensive new drug, they got
the very cheap old drug, ketoconazole. They might do just as well, or it might
be that the new drug has some advantage—until we did the study we wouldn’t
know.
The kicker that Mailankody and Prasad now note is—how would
this new study be paid for? No way that the drug company that’s making a mint off
abiraterone is going to bankroll a study that might pull the rug out from under
its golden goose. So suppose some neutral investigators try to organize the
study? Well, assuming that for the very same reasons, the manufacturer won’t
just give away abiraterone for free (especially knowing for what purpose it’s
going to be used), the investigators would have to pay market price and buy the
drug. And the authors calculate that for a study large enough to answer the
question of non-inferiority of ketoconazole, the cost of the drug alone—forget
the rest of the cost of the study—would be about $69 million. In other words,
no study of this sort will ever be done.
These authors also work for the NIH, and so are also
apparently leery of saying anything controversial, and so don’t offer any
proposals for a solution to this problem.
OK, so we have three articles in the same issue of NEJM, all of which have the same basic theme—in the name of profits, the drug industry is working contrary to the public health and the advancement of science. This is what old-time economist Kenneth Arrow famously called the market failure of health care—it simply does not follow the laws of supply and demand. Those who continue to extol the supposedly “free” market as the right way to manage all of our affairs, pharmaceuticals and health included, have to stick their heads in the sand and pretend that market failure never happens. As this blog has shown extensively, it happens all the time.
Thursday, April 10, 2014
More on Flu Drugs and the Broken Drug Research System
We’ve discussed the debate over oseltamivir (Tamiflu) and
the problems in determining whether it offers advantages to flu patients, given
how hard reviewers had to search to get all the data:
http://brodyhooked.blogspot.com/2009/12/bmj-medical-research-is-broken.htmlhttp://brodyhooked.blogspot.com/2012/09/more-on-tamiflu-challenges-of-getting.html
The story led the editor of BMJ back in 2009 to proclaim about the scientific evaluation of
drugs, “The current system isn’t
working. Worse than that, it gives a false sense of security.”
The latest BMJ readdresses the oseltamivir story,
and if the system was broken in 2009, it has not gotten fixed since. The
summaries of what they have to say can be found in two editorials:
http://www.bmj.com/content/348/bmj.g2630http://www.bmj.com/content/348/bmj.g2548?ijkey=ded5662cf46f75236fb45a9cda0bb2a671ec0e98&keytype2=tf_ipsecsha&linkType=FULL&journalCode=bmj&resid=348/apr09_2/g2548&atom=/bmj/348/bmj.g2630.atom
In the previous
blog posts, I reviewed how difficult it was for the authors of a Cochrane
review of neuroaminidase inhibitors for influenza (the class of drugs to which
oseltamivir belongs) to get their hands on all the relevant data from
unpublished studies conducted by the manufacturer. Once they did get a reasonable
amount of data, they found the data so voluminous that it took several
person-years of labor to sort through it all. But they persevered, and what we
now know is that drugs like oseltamivir may shorten your bout of flu, if you
start taking the drug within the first two days of symptoms, by half a day. It
may cause a number of worrisome side effects. And we have no reason to believe
that the drug will prevent the bad complications of influenza requiring
hospitalization and admission to an ICU (which is the anticipated benefit
that led the WHO to champion the drug and many nations to spend billions of
dollars stockpiling the drug as a public health precaution).
We also know that
the published studies on these drugs, virtually all of which were conducted by
the manufacturers, overstated the benefits and understated the adverse
reactions. In short, if you went to legitimate, prestigious medical journals
for information, as all us docs were taught to do in med school, you’d be
mostly clueless.
The editors of BMJ gamely propose a list of reforms.
But I believe that two conclusions are inescapable. First, if it took this much
time and effort to get the goods on oseltamivir—and we still don’t know what
the drug is really good for, if anything, since the really important studies of
its potential value have not yet been conducted—then what about the hundreds of
other drugs that have been introduced with great fanfare in the last few
decades, and none of which have been subjected to anything like this degree of inquiry
and investigation? Second, on what basis can we claim any longer that we should
have any faith at all in drug research sponsored by manufacturers?
Tuesday, April 8, 2014
AMC Leaders on Corporate Boards—A Modest Proposal
Dr. Roy Poses over at Health Care Renewal has for some time
been speaking out about conflicts of interest posed by leaders of academic
medicine and supposedly “not-for-profit” health systems who also rake in big
bucks for sitting on the boards of large corporations such as drug companies
and other firms that often do business with those same health centers. He most
recently called attention to a research letter in JAMA that provides some of the first data on the frequency of these
ties (see link in blog post):
http://hcrenewal.blogspot.com/2014/04/finally-article-in-large-circulation.html
http://hcrenewal.blogspot.com/2014/04/finally-article-in-large-circulation.html
Dr. Poses notes a number of serious ethical concerns that
result from these board relationships. He is most worried about the way that a
small group of very wealthy corporate insiders seem to have formed an
old-boys-and-girls club that runs not only the corporate sphere but increasingly
the world of health care as well, and how in the process the interests of
ordinary folk get left behind. There is also the narrower question of the role
of these people on those corporate boards which forms a sort of Catch-22. These
corporations, as we have detailed ad nauseam in this blog, often take actions
that go against the public interest. If (say) a university president is a
member of the board of directors, then the prez presumably should speak up and
demand that the corporation cease and desist all such behaviors. If the prez
says that really, don’t blame him, he has no control over that behavior, then
he is admitting that he’s failed in his role as a corporate overseer, which is
what legally the board of directors is supposed to be about.
In the middle of this debate I have one of my occasional
modest proposals. It does not address the deeper issues, which would entail
leaders of academic medical and health centers not being on those corporate
boards at all--but see my Modest Prediction at the end.
Whenever do-gooders like us complain about these conflicts
of interest, apologists for the One Percent crowd claim that after all, these
board relationships are very valuable for the university or the AMC or the
health system. They expose the board to the presumably enlightened views of
academic and health care leaders. They expose the leaders to important
information about what’s happening on the corporate side, thereby stimulating
productive university-industry partnerships for the future. So how could anyone
be so narrow-minded as to object to these relationships?
Hence my modest proposal—demand that any academic or
health care leader who serves on a corporate board do so without pay and at
his/her own expense for travel and lodging. If their being on the board
is so all-fired valuable to the academic or health institution, then let that
board service be a part of the CEO’s job at that institution. Last I heard,
none of these high rollers were being underpaid for their leadership roles.
They have funds to cover their activities if they travel on university or
hospital business, so why not regard board service under that category?
I would along with the modest proposal make a modest
prediction. If you ceased paying these CEOs personally for their board service,
commonly nowadays in the six-figure-per-year range, suddenly none of these CEOs
would want to be on corporate boards any more. So much, if so, for all the
wonderful intellectual advantages of board service and industry relationships.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)